StudyBoss » Great Depression » Causes of the Great Depression

Causes of the Great Depression

In 1929 the stock market crashed, triggering the worst depression ever in U. S. history, which lasted for about a decade. During the 1920s, the unequal distribution of wealth and the stock market speculation combined to create an unstable economy by the end of the decade. The unequal distribution of the wealth had several outlets. Money was distributed between industry and agriculture within the U. S. ; in social classes, between the rich and middle class; and lastly in world markets, between America and Europe. Due to the imbalance of the wealth, the economy became very unstable.

The stock market crashed because of the excessive speculation in the 1920s, which made the stock market artificially high (Galbraith 175). The poor distribution of the wealth, excessive speculation, and the stock market crashes caused the U. S. economy to fail, signaling the start of the Great Depression. The 1920s were a time when the American people and the economy were thriving. This period of time was called the Roaring Twenties. Unemployment dropped as low as 3 percent, prices held steady, and the gross national product climbed from $70 billion in 1922 to nearly $100 billion in1929 (EV 525).

However, the prosperity of the 1920s was not shared evenly among the social classes in America. A study conducted by the Brookings Institution stated, 78 percent of all American families had incomes of less than $3,000. Forty percent had family incomes of less than $1,500. Only 2. 3 percent of the population enjoyed incomes of over $10,000. Sixty thousand American families held savings which amounted to the total held by the bottom 25 million families. (Goldston 26). The 40 percent of Americans at the lowest end of the economic scale received only 12 percent of the national income by 1929 (EV 549).

This maldistribution of income between the rich and the middle class increased throughout the 1920s. A major reason for this large and growing gap between the upper class and the working class Americans was that the manufacturing output increased throughout this period. As the production costs fell, wages went up slowly, and prices for goods remained at a constant. The majority of the benefits created by increased productivity fell into the hands of corporate owners. The federal government also helped to make the growing gap between the upper and middle classes.

President Calvin Coolidges administration favored business, and as a result, the wealthy invested in these businesses. An example of this type of legislation is the Revenue Act of 1926, which significantly reduced income and inheritance taxes (Goldston 23). The introduction of credit to the American public proved to choke the economy rather than to stimulate it. To make an economy run properly, the total demand must equal total supply. The economy of the 1920s produced an over supply of goods. It was not that the surplus products were not wanted, but that the people who needed them could not afford the products.

The working class spent most of their money on things they needed: food, shelter, and clothes. They also purchased some luxury items, but their income limited them to only a few of these purchases. Meanwhile, the rich were enjoying their increased profits. While the vast majority did not have enough money to satisfy all of their material wants and needs, the manufactures continued to produce surplus goods. Recognizing that the surpluses could be sold if consumers were financially able to buy them, the concept of buying on credit was established. Credit was immediately popular.

Nearing the end of the decade, 75 percent of all automobiles were purchased on credit (EV 526). The credit system created artificial demand for products which people could not usually buy. People could not spend their regular wages to purchase products, because much of their income went toward their credit payments. The poor distribution of wealth within the U. S extended to entire industries, helping one at the expense of another. The prosperity of the decade was not shared among the industries equally. While the automotive industry was thriving in the 1920s, some industries, such as agriculture, were declining steadily.

Most of the industries that were prospering in the 1920s were in some way linked to the automobile or radio industries. The automotive industry was the crutch that supported other industries (Galbraith 7). The first industries to prosper were those that made materials for cars: steel industries and other metal industries, glass, leather, and textile industries. Oil companies such as Texaco, Gulf, and Atlantic rose by 250 percent in production, and annual oil imports crept up to 76 million barrels (EV 532). Also prospering during the 1920s were businesses dependent upon the radio industry.

Radio stations, electronic stores, and electricity companies all needed the radio to survive. By 1930, 40 percent of all Americans had radios (EV 533). In 1926 major broadcasting companies started appearing, such as NBC and CBS. The advertising industry was also becoming reliant upon the radio as a method of advertising. There are several factors that lead to the prosperity in the automotive and radio industries. First, during World War I both the automobile and the radio were significantly improved upon. Due to the demands of the war, automobiles, radios, and the parts necessary to build these things were being produced in large quantities.

The foundation existed for the auto and radio industries to take off. Second, due to the federal governments easing of credit, money was available to invest in these industries. The government favored the new industries better than the agriculture. During WWI, the government had subsidized farms, and paid high prices for wheat and other grains. They told farmers to produce more food for the war effort. However, as soon as the war ended the U. S. stopped its policies to help farmers. Farmers fell into debt; farm prices and food prices dropped (Personal Interview).

The problem with such heavy concentrations of wealth and such massive dependence upon essentially two industries is similar to the problem with few people having too much wealth. The economy is reliant on those industries to expand and grow in order to prosper. If those two industries, the automotive and radio industries, were to slow down or stop, so would the entire economy. When they slowed down, so did the U. S. economy. The problem with the automobile and radio industries was that they could not expand for the simple reason that people could and would buy only so many cars and radios.

When the auto and radio industries failed, all their dependents fell with them. One of the last major instabilities of the American economy had to do with large-scale international wealth distribution problems. While America was prospering in the 1920s, European nations were struggling to rebuild themselves after the damage of the war. During World War I, the U. S. government lent its European allies $7 billion, and then another $3. 3 billion by 1920 (Galbriath 187). American foreign lending continued in the 1920s climbing to $1. 25 billion in 1927 and 1928 (Goldston 17).

The nations that borrowed money from the U. S. were in no position to pay off their debts. If they paid back the loans, they would ruin their currency. To make matters worse, U. S. placed tariffs on imports from foreign countries in order to protect American business. The effect of these tariffs was that Europeans were unable to sell their own goods in the U. S. in reasonable quantities. If the U. S would not buy from European markets, then there was no way for them to buy from the Americans, or even to pay interest on U. S. loans. This weakness in the international economy contributed to the Great Depression.

Mass speculation went on throughout the late 1920s. In from early 1928 to September 1929, the Dow Jones Industrial Average rose from 191 to 381 (Galbraith 70-73). Company earnings became of little interest; as long as stock prices continued to rise, huge profits could be made. By purchasing stocks on margin, one could buy stocks without the money to purchase them. Investors went crazy with this asset. By mid 1929, the total of outstanding brokers loans was over $8. 5 billion (Goldston 36). Interest rates for broker loans were reaching the sky, going as high as twenty percent in March 1929 (Goldston 36).

Prices had been drifting downward, but speculators continued to flock to the market. Then, on Monday, October 21, prices started to fall quickly. The stocks started to sell quickly. This caused the collapse to happen faster. Prices stabilized a little, but then on Black Thursday, October 24, everything fell apart again. By this time investors had lost confidence in the market. A group of leading bankers stepped in to try to stimulate the market. But that was not enough to keep prices from falling. Then on Black Tuesday, 16. 4 million shares changed hands (EV 548).

Stocks fell so much, that at many times during the day no buyers were available at any price (EV 549). This speculation and the resulting stock market crash acted as a trigger to the already unstable U. S. economy. Due to the poor distribution of wealth, the economy of the 1920s was one very much dependent upon confidence. President Hoover stated, the crisis has been isolated to the stock market itself. (Docs Hoover). The market crash proved this confidence to be wrong. The rich stopped spending on luxury items, and the middle and lower classes stopped using credit in fear of losing their jobs and defaulting on their loans.

As a result, industrial production fell by nine percent causing people to lose their jobs and default on loans (Galbraith 42). Industries started to fall apart around the automobile and radio industries. The rich refused to make loans to foreign countries for fear of going bankrupt. Foreigners stopped buying U. S. goods. Banks started to go under, stores closed up. President Hoover did not act in time to stop the country from going further into a depression (Docs Hoover). Unemployment had reached 13 million in 1932 (EV 549); the country went quickly downhill. The start of the Great Depression was setting in.

Cite This Work

To export a reference to this article please select a referencing style below:

Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.

Leave a Comment

StudyBoss » Great Depression » Causes of the Great Depression

Causes of The Great Depression

The Great Depression was the worst economic slump ever in U. S. history, and one which spread to virtually all of the industrialized world. The depression began in late 1929 and lasted for about a decade. Many factors played a role in bringing about the depression; however, the main cause for the Great Depression was the combination of the greatly unequal distribution of wealth throughout the 1920’s, and the extensive stock market speculation that took place during the latter part that same decade. The maldistribution of wealth in the 1920’s existed on many levels.

Money was distributed disparately etween the rich and the middle-class, between industry and agriculture within the United States, and between the U. S. and Europe. This imbalance of wealth created an unstable economy. The excessive speculation in the late 1920’s kept the stock market artificially high, but eventually lead to large market crashes. These market crashes, combined with the maldistribution of wealth, caused the American economy to capsize. The “roaring twenties” was an era when our country prospered tremendously.

The nation’s total realized income rose from $74. billion in 1923 to $89 billion in 1929(end note 1). However, the ewards of the “Coolidge Prosperity” of the 1920’s were not shared evenly among all Americans. According to a study done by the Brookings Institute, in 1929 the top 0. 1% of Americans had a combined income equal to the bottom 42%(end note 2). That same top 0. 1% of Americans in 1929 controlled 34% of all savings, while 80% of Americans had no savings at all(end note 3). Automotive industry mogul Henry Ford provides a striking example of the unequal distribution of wealth between the rich and the middle-class.

Henry Ford reported a personal income of $14 million(end note 4) in the same year that the average ersonal income was $750(end note 5). By present day ezdards, where the average yearly income in the U. S. is around $18,500(end note 6), Mr. Ford would be earning over $345 million a year! This maldistribution of income between the rich and the middle class grew throughout the 1920’s. While the disposable income per capita rose 9% from 1920 to 1929, those with income within the top 1% enjoyed a stupendous 75% increase in per capita disposable income(end note 7).

A major reason for this large and growing gap between the rich and the working-class people was the increased manufacturing output throughout this period. From 1923-1929 the average output per worker increased 32% in manufacturing(end note 8). During that same period of time average wages for manufacturing jobs increased only 8%(end note 9). Thus wages increased at a rate one fourth as fast as productivity increased. As production costs fell quickly, wages rose slowly, and prices remained conezt, the bulk benefit of the increased productivity went into corporate profits.

In fact, from 1923-1929 corporate profits rose 62% and dividends rose 65%(end note 10). The federal government also contributed to the growing gap between the rich and middle-class. Calvin Coolidge’s administration and the conservative-controlled government) favored business, and as a result the wealthy who invested in these businesses. An example of legislation to this purpose is the Revenue Act of 1926, signed by President Coolidge on February 26, 1926, which reduced federal income and inheritance taxes dramatically(end note 11).

Andrew Mellon, Coolidge’s Secretary of the Treasury, was the main force behind these and other tax cuts throughout the 1920’s. In effect, he was able to lower federal taxes such that a man with a million-dollar annual income had his federal taxes reduced from $600,000 to $200,000(end note 12). Even the Supreme Court played a role in expanding the gap between the socioeconomic classes. In the 1923 case Adkins v. Children’s Hospital, the Supreme Court ruled minimum-wage legislation unconstitutional(end note 13).

The large and growing disparity of wealth between the well-to-do and the middle-income citizens made the U. S. economy unstable. For an economy to function properly, total demand must equal total supply. In an economy with such disparate distribution of income it is not assured that demand will always equal supply. Essentially what happened in the 1920’s was that there was an oversupply of goods. It was not that the surplus products of industrialized society were not wanted, but rather that those whose needs were not satiated could not afford more, whereas the wealthy were satiated by spending only a small portion of their income.

A 1932 article in Current History articulates the problems of this maldistribution of wealth: “We still pray to be given each day our daily bread. Yet there is too much bread, too much wheat and corn, meat and oil and almost every other commodity required by man for his subsistence and material happiness. We are not able to purchase the abundance that modern ethods of agriculture, mining and manufacturing make available in such bountiful quantities(end note 14). ” Three quarters of the U. S. population would spend essentially all of their yearly incomes to purchase consumer goods such as food, clothes, radios, and cars.

These were the poor and middle class: families with incomes around, or usually less than, $2,500 a year. The bottom three quarters of the population had an aggregate income of less than 45% of the combined national income; the top 25% of the population took in more than 55% of the national income(end note 15). While the wealthy oo purchased consumer goods, a family earning $100,000 could not be expected to eat 40 times more than a family that only earned $2,500 a year, or buy 40 cars, 40 radios, or 40 houses.

Through such a period of imbalance, the U. S. ame to rely upon two things in order for the economy to remain on an even keel: credit sales, and luxury spending and investment from the rich. One obvious solution to the problem of the vast majority of the population not having enough money to satisfy all their needs was to let those who wanted goods buy products on credit. The concept of buying now and paying later caught on quickly. By the end of the 1920’s 60% of cars and 80% of radios were bought on installment credit(end note 16). Between 1925 and 1929 the total amount of outezding installment credit more than doubled from $1. 38 billion to around $3 billion(end note 17).

Installment credit allowed one to “telescope the future into the present”, as the President’s Committee on Social Trends noted(end note 18). This strategy created artificial demand for products which people could not ordinarily afford. It put off the day of reckoning, but it made the downfall worse when it came. By telescoping the future into the present, when “the future” arrived, here was little to buy that hadn’t already been bought. In addition, people could not longer use their regular wages to purchase whatever items they didn’t have yet, because so much of the wages went to paying back past purchases.

The U. S. economy was also reliant upon luxury spending and investment from the rich to stay afloat during the 1920’s. The significant problem with this reliance was that luxury spending and investment were based on the wealthy’s confidence in the U. S. economy. If conditions were to take a downturn (as they did with the market crashed in fall and winter 1929), this spending and investment would low to a halt. While savings and investment are important for an economy to stay balanced, at excessive levels they are not good. Greater investment usually means greater productivity.

However, since the rewards of the increased productivity were not being distributed equally, the problems of income distribution (and of overproduction) were only made worse. Lastly, the search for ever greater returns on investment lead to wide-spread market speculation. Maldistribution of wealth within our nation was not limited to only socioeconomic classes, but to entire industries. In 1929 a mere 00 corporations controlled approximately half of all corporate wealth(end note 19). While the automotive industry was thriving in the 1920’s, some industries, agriculture in particular, were declining steadily.

In 1921, the same year that Ford Motor Company reported record assets of more than $345 million, farm prices plummeted, and the price of food fell nearly 72% due to a huge surplus(end note 20). While the average per capita income in 1929 was $750 a year for all Americans, the average annual income for someone working in agriculture was only $273(end note 21). The prosperity of the 1920’s as simply not shared among industries evenly. In fact, most of the industries that were prospering in the 1920’s were in some way linked to the automotive industry or to the radio industry.

The automotive industry was the driving force behind many other booming industries in the 1920’s. By 1928, with over 21 million cars on the roads, there was roughly one car for every six Americans(end note 22). The first industries to prosper were those that made materials for cars. The booming steel industry sold roughly 15% of its products to the automobile industry(end note 23). The nickel, lead, and other metal industries capitalized similarly. The new closed cars of the 1920’s benefited the glass, leather, and textile industries greatly.

And manufacturers of the rubber tires that these cars used grew even faster than the automobile industry itself, for each car would probably need more than one set of tires over the course of its life. The fuel industry also profited and expanded. Companies such as Ethyl Corporation made millions with items such as new “knock-free” fuel additives for cars(end note 24).

In addition, “tourist homes” (hotels and motels) opened up everywhere. With such a wealthy upper-class many luxury hotels were needed. In 1924 alone, hotels such as the Mayflower (Washington D. C. ), the Parker House (Boston), The Palmer House (Chicago), and the Peabody (Memphis) opened their doors(end note 25). Lastly, and possibly most importantly, the construction industry benefited tremendously from the automobile. With the growing number of cars, there was a big demand for paved roads. During the 1920’s Americans spent more than a $1 billion each year on the construction and maintenance of highways, and at least another $400 million annually for city streets(end note 26). But the automotive industry affected construction far more than that.

The automobile had been central to the urbanization of the country in the 1920’s because so many other industries relied upon it. With urbanization came the need to build many more apartment buildings, factories, offices, and stores. From 1919 to 1928 the construction industry grew by around $5 billion dollars, nearly 50%(end note 27). Also prospering during the 1920’s were businesses dependent upon the radio business. Radio stations, electronic stores, and electricity companies all needed the radio to survive, and relied upon the conezt growth of the radio market to expand and grow themselves.

By 930, 40% of American families had radios(end note 28). In 1926 major broadcasting companies started appearing, such as the National Broadcasting Company. The advertising industry was also becoming heavily reliant upon the radio both as a product to be advertised, and as a method of advertising. Several factors lead to the concentration of wealth and prosperity into the automotive and radio industries. First, during World War I both the automobile and the radio were significantly improved upon. Both had existed before, but radio had been mostly experimental.

Due to the demands of the war, by 1920 automobiles, adios, and the parts necessary to build these things were being produced in large quantities; the work force in these industries had been formed and had become experienced. Manufacturing plants were already in place. The infrastructure existed for the automotive and radio industries to take off. Second, due to federal government’s easing of credit, money was available to invest in these industries. Thanks to pressure from President Coolidge and the business world, the Federal Reserve Board kept the rediscount rate low.

The federal government favored the new industries as opposed to agriculture. During World War I the federal government had subsidized farms, and payed absurdly high prices for wheat and other grains. The federal government had encouraged farmers to buy more land, to modernize their methods with the latest in farm technology, and to produce more food. This made sense during that war when war-ravaged Europe had to be fed too. However as soon as the war ended, the U. S. abruptly stopped its policies to help farmers.

During the war the United States government had paid an unheard of $2 a bushel for wheat, but by 1920 wheat prices had fallen to as low as 67 cents a bushel(end note 29). Farmers fell into debt; farm prices and food prices tumbled. Although modest attempts to help farmers were made in 1923 with the Agricultural Credits Act, farmers were generally left out in the cold by the government. The problem with such heavy concentrations of wealth and such massive dependence upon essentially two industries is similar to the problem with few people having too much wealth.

The economy is reliant upon those industries to expand and grow and invest in order to prosper. If those two industries, the automotive and radio industries, were to slow down or stop, so would the entire economy. While the economy did prosper greatly in the 1920’s, because this prosperity wasn’t balanced between different industries, when those industries that had all the wealth concentrated in them slowed down, the whole economy did. The fundamental problem with the automobile and radio industries was that they could not expand ad infinitum for the simple reason that people could and would buy only so many cars and radios.

When the automotive and radio industries went down all their dependents, essentially all of American industry, fell. Because it had been ignored, agriculture, which was still a fairly large segment of he economy, was already in ruin when American industry fell. A last major instability of the American economy had to do with large-scale international wealth distribution problems. While America was prospering in the 1920’s, European nations were struggling to rebuild themselves after the damage of war.

During World War I the U. S. government lent its European allies $7 billion, and then another $3. billion by 1920(end note 30). By the Dawes Plan of 1924 the U. S. started lending to Axis Germany. American foreign lending continued in the 1920’s climbing to $900 million in 1924, and $1. 25 billion in 1927 nd 1928(end note 31). Of these funds, more than 90% were used by the European allies to purchase U. S. goods(end note 32).

The nations the U. S. had lent money to (Britain, Italy, France, Belgium, Russia, Yugoslavia, Estonia, Poland, and others) were in no position to pay off the debts. Their gold had flowed into the U. S. uring and immediately after the war in great quantity; they couldn’t send more gold without completely ruining their currencies. Historian John D. Hicks describes the Allied attitude towards U. S. loan repayment: “In their view the war was fought for a common objective, and the ictory was as essential for the safety of the United States as for their own. The United States had entered the struggle late, and had poured forth no such contribution in lives and losses as the Allies had made.

It had paid in dollars, not in death and destruction, and now it wanted its dollars back(end note 33). There were several causes to this awkward distribution of wealth between U. S. and its European counterparts. Most obvious is that fact that World War I had devastated European business. Factories, homes, and farms had been destroyed in the war. It would take time and money to recuperate. Equally important to causing the disparate distribution of wealth was tariff policy of the United States. The United States had traditionally placed tariffs on imports from foreign countries in order to protect American business. However these tariffs reached an all-time high in the 1920’s and early 1930’s.

Starting with the Fordney-McCumber Act of 1922 and ending with the Hawley-Smoot Tariff of 1930, the United States increased many tariffs by 100% or more(end note 34). The effect of these tariffs was that Europeans were unable to sell their own goods in the United States in reasonable quantities. In the 1920’s the United States was trying “to be the world’s banker, food producer, and manufacturer, but to buy as little as possible from the world in return. “(end note 35) This attempt to have a coneztly favorable trade balance could not succeed for long.

The United States maintained high trade barriers so as to protect American business, but if the United States would not buy from our European counterparts, then there was no way for them to buy from the Americans, or even to pay interest on U. S. loans. The weakness of the international economy certainly contributed to the Great Depression. Europe was reliant upon U. S. loans to buy U. S. goods, and the U. S. needed Europe to buy these goods to prosper. By 1929 10% of American gross national product went into exports(end note 36). When the foreign countries became no longer able to buy U. S. goods, U. S. xports fell 30% immediately.

That $1. 5 billion of foreign sales lost between 1929 to 1933 was fully one eighth of all lost American sales in the early years of the depression(end note 37). Mass speculation went on throughout the late 1920’s. In 1929 alone, a record volume of 1,124,800,410 shares were traded on the New York Stock Exchange(end note 38). From early 1928 to September 1929 he Dow Jones Industrial Average rose from 191 to 381(end note 39). This sort of profit was irresistible to investors. Company earnings became of little interest; as long as stock prices continued to rise huge profits could be made.

One such example is RCA corporation, whose stock price leapt from 85 to 420 during 1928, even though it had not yet paid a single dividend(end note 40). Even these returns of over 100% were no measure of the possibility for investors of the time. Through the miracle of buying stocks on margin, one could buy stocks without the money to purchase them. Buying stocks on margin functioned uch the same way as buying a car on credit. Using the example of RCA, a Mr. John Doe could buy 1 share of the company by putting up $10 of his own, and borrowing $75 from his broker.

If he sold the stock at $420 a year later he would have turned his original investment of just $10 into $341. 25 ($420 minus the $75 and 5% interest owed to the broker). That makes a return of over 3400%! Investors’ craze over the proposition of profits like this drove the market to absurdly high levels. By mid 1929 the total of outezding brokers’ loans was over $7 billion(end note 41); in the next three months that number would each $8. 5 billion(end note 42). Interest rates for brokers loans were reaching the sky, going as high as 20% in March 1929(end note 43).

The speculative boom in the stock market was based upon confidence. In the same way, the huge market crashes of 1929 were based on fear. Prices had been drifting downward since September 3, but generally people where optimistic. Speculators continued to flock to the market. Then, on Monday October 21 prices started to fall quickly. The volume was so great that the ticker fell behind(end note 44). Investors became fearful. Knowing that prices were falling, but not by ow much, they started selling quickly. This caused the collapse to happen faster.

Prices stabilized a little on Tuesday and Wednesday, but then on Black Thursday, October 24, everything fell apart again. By this time most major investors had lost confidence in the market. Once enough investors had decided the boom was over, it was over. Partial recovery was achieved on Friday and Saturday when a group of leading bankers stepped in to try to stop the crash. But then on Monday the 28th prices started dropping again. By the end of the day the market had fallen 13%(end note 45). The next day, Black Tuesday an nprecedented 16. 4 million shares changed hands(end note 46).

Stocks fell so much, that at many times during the day no buyers were available at any price(end note 47). This speculation and the resulting stock market crashes acted as a trigger to the already unstable U. S. economy. Due to the maldistribution of wealth, the economy of the 1920’s was one very much dependent upon confidence. The market crashes undermined this confidence. The rich stopped spending on luxury items, and slowed investments. The middle-class and poor stopped buying things with installment credit for fear of loosing their jobs, and not being able o pay the interest.

As a result industrial production fell by more than 9% between the market crashes in October and December 1929(end note 48). As a result jobs were lost, and soon people starting defaulting on their interest payment. Radios and cars bought with installment credit had to be returned. All of the sudden warehouses were piling up with inventory. The thriving industries that had been connected with the automobile and radio industries started falling apart. Without a car people did not need fuel or tires; without a radio people had less need for electricity.

On the international cene, the rich had practically stopped lending money to foreign countries. With such tremendous profits to be made in the stock market nobody wanted to make low interest loans. To protect the nation’s businesses the U. S. imposed higher trade barriers (Hawley-Smoot Tariff of 1930). Foreigners stopped buying American products. More jobs were lost, more stores were closed, more banks went under, and more factories closed. Unemployment grew to five million in 1930, and up to thirteen million in 1932(end note 49). The country spiraled quickly into catastrophe. The Great Depression had begun.

Cite This Work

To export a reference to this article please select a referencing style below:

Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.
Reference Copied to Clipboard.

Leave a Comment